House Democrats introduce carbon pricing measure

By Zack Budryk, The Hill, April 1, 2021

Four House Democrats on Thursday reintroduced legislation to establish a carbon pricing system in the U.S.

The bill would price carbon at $15 per metric ton of carbon dioxide equivalent, with the price increasing $10 a year. The measure’s sponsors wrote that it would reduce carbon pollution by as much as 45 percent by 2030 and net zero by 2050.

The sponsors include Reps. Ted Deutch (D-Fla.), Charlie Crist (D-Fla.), Judy Chu (D-Calif.), Anna Eshoo (D-Calif.) and Scott Peters (D-Calif.).

“The pandemic may have temporarily interrupted the scale of global carbon emissions, but we need a robust plan that makes lasting changes to our energy sector. We're proposing a market-based solution to put a price on carbon and drive the transition to cleaner energy sources. Returning 100% of the net revenue back to American families will not only cover any increase in energy costs but also give extra support to those continuing to struggle financially from the pandemic,” Deutch said in a statement Thursday.

“Congress must move forward with this popular and effective plan to curb rising emissions and address a major contributor to climate change,” he added.

The legislation was first introduced in 2019. However, the reintroduction comes after one of the fossil fuel industry’s biggest lobbying groups, the American Petroleum Institute (API), announced its backing for carbon pricing after vocally opposing it for years. The API did not endorse a specific pricing system but said it was open to a cap-and-trade plan after spearheading lobbying against such a plan under the Obama administration.

Addressing the Biden administration’s target of net zero carbon emissions by 2050, API President and CEO Mike Sommers said last week that “there’s no way it is feasible without technologies that aren’t currently in the marketplace today. We think that the best way to do that is through a market based carbon-pricing mechanism that isn’t picking winners and losers.”

https://thehill.com/policy/energy-environment/545988-house-democrats-introduce-carbon-pricing-measure?rl=1

Carbon Tax Sidelined in Biden’s Push on Climate, Taxes

President, some Democrats fret over inequities from pricing carbon, despite lack of evidence

Column by Greg Ip, The Wall Street Journal, March 24, 2021

There is no more effective way for President Biden to meet his aggressive climate goals than a carbon tax. The timing seems ripe: his Treasury Secretary, Janet Yellen, has been a prominent advocate. Big business has flipped from opponent to proponent. Republican opposition is no longer monolithic.

But a carbon tax lacks support where it matters most: with Mr. Biden and the Democratic base. Progressive Democrats claim a carbon tax and its close cousin, cap-and-trade, are unfair to the poor and racial minorities. And a carbon tax appears to conflict with Mr. Biden’s promise not to raise taxes on any household earning less than $400,000 a year.

So as Mr. Biden prepares a regulatory and infrastructure package aimed at driving net greenhouse gas emissions to zero in electricity by 2035 and the entire economy by 2050, he is fighting with one hand tied behind his back.

A carbon price incentivizes consumers, producers and investors to substitute low- or no-carbon energy technology for fossil fuels more smoothly and cheaply than subsidies and rules. This has long been self-evident to economists, including Ms. Yellen. She is a founding member of the Climate Leadership Council, a bipartisan group that has put forward a detailed plan for a carbon tax starting at $43 per ton with proceeds rebated to households as a “carbon dividend.”

In response to questions from senators at her confirmation hearing, Ms. Yellen said, “We cannot solve the climate crisis without effective carbon pricing.” While a carbon tax is the most direct way to price carbon, it isn’t the only one. With cap and trade, total greenhouse gas emissions are capped and companies purchase permits to emit one ton of gas. The more expensive the permit, the greater the incentive to reduce emissions. Cap and trade was the centerpiece of the last major effort to price carbon, in 2010. It ultimately failed due to opposition from business, Republicans and some Democrats.

Since then, opposition has softened: the U.S. Chamber of Commerce favors a “market-based” approach to carbon reductions, Business Roundtable now backs a price on carbon, and even the American Petroleum Institute is weighing the same. Most Republicans still oppose aggressive action on climate, but in recent months Sens. Mitt Romney (R., Utah), Lindsey Graham (R., S.C.) and Lisa Murkowski (R., Alaska) have all expressed openness to carbon pricing.

Yet just as others are moving toward a carbon price, progressive Democrats are moving away. They argue that the poor, Blacks and Hispanics are disproportionately harmed by carbon taxes or the pollutants that businesses can release on nearby communities under a cap and trade system. Mary Nichols, who oversaw California’s cap and trade system, was passed over as head of Mr. Biden’s Environmental Protection Agency in the face of activists’ opposition. A coalition of environmental groups accused her of “pushing market-based approaches to the climate crisis at the expense of the health and well-being of California’s communities of color.”

But empirical evidence suggests otherwise. California’s carbon market actually narrowed disparities in exposure to particulates, nitrogen oxides and sulfur oxides, according to a study by economists Danae Hernandez-Cortes and Kyle Meng of the University of California, Santa Barbara. An older federal program that allows higher-polluting plants to buy offsets from less-polluting plants didn’t disproportionately move pollution to lower-income communities or communities of color, according to a separate study by Joseph Shapiro and Reed Walker, economists at the University of California, Berkeley.

Whether carbon taxes hurt the poor depends on what is done with the revenue. The Climate Leadership Council estimates its carbon tax would finance $2,000 in carbon dividends a year for a family of four, and the 80% lowest-income families end up better off. Regulatory alternatives aren’t necessarily better: renewable-fuel requirements can raise electricity prices and disproportionately hurt poor families who devote more of their budget to power.

Many Democratic politicos have concluded a carbon tax is a political loser with voters opposing it. The question is, compared with what? Progressives’ beloved Green New Deal polls no better. Mr. Biden and Congress have floated a range of incentives, tax credits, regulations and investments aimed at driving down emissions, many of which, individually, are quite popular. But they’re not enough. A new study by Rhodium Group estimates all such measures, combined, wouldn’t put the U.S. electricity sector on a path to net zero by 2035.

So if Mr. Biden is serious about his emissions targets, a carbon price may become harder to avoid. His administration is already considering taxing imports for their carbon content. Without a similar levy on domestically-made goods, the U.S. could face retaliation from trading partners. He also plans to raise taxes, in part to pay for a big boost to the child tax credit, which slashes child poverty. If he wants a tax that helps the poor, defrays the deficit and combats climate change, there is one waiting in the wings.

https://www.wsj.com/articles/support-for-carbon-tax-grows-except-where-it-matters-most-11616590985?mod=searchresults_pos1&page=1

PRG reaction: This is an insightful column that deserves wide attention. Note, though, that analysis has found that if at least 50 percent of the tax revenues are issued as dividends, and are means-tested, the poor are better off. Also, polling shows strong support for levying carbon fees on fossil fuel companies. Most progressives would support a price mechanism if it complemented other approaches to tackling the climate problem.


The danger of climate change is imminent. The Senate must approve a strong policy.

Editorial, The Washington Post, March 18, 2021

THERE HAVE been many moments when it seemed as though the United States would tackle climate change, only for hopes to be dashed. Now, it has another chance. President Biden promised to put global warming at the top of his agenda, and congressional Democrats, for now clinging to narrow majorities, are beginning to offer plans.

The danger is imminent. The world cannot afford another round of nice-sounding proposals followed by inaction. Congress must go big on climate change.

One plan, the sprawling Clean Future Act, released earlier this month by the leaders of several House committees, would have the country reach net-zero greenhouse emissions by mid-century, starting with massive decarbonization of the electricity sector over the next decade. The bill would require utilities to derive increasing amounts of their electricity from clean sources, which include renewables, nuclear power and, for a limited time and at a discounted rate, natural-gas-fired power plants. The bill would invest in electric car infrastructure, compensate coal country for lost jobs and ask states to develop emissions-cutting plans that would address any areas federal programs failed to cover.

Elements of the Clean Future Act might have bipartisan appeal, but the package as a whole is unlikely to attract GOP support. No doubt sensing that Democrats would seek to impose emissions regulations and mandates, as does the Clean Future Act, some Republicans and industry players have begun talking up market-based reforms that would be less costly and disruptive. Major oil companies now favor taxing at some level the carbon content of fuels such as gasoline. Sen. Mitt Romney (R-Utah) called for such a tax in February. Even the American Petroleum Institute, a longtime opponent of climate action, is reportedly considering endorsing a carbon tax.

These voices should have spoken up a decade ago. Democrats have been reluctant to embrace such a plan since 2010, when they proposed a carbon pricing bill and slammed into a wall of coal-state and industry opposition. Since then, the left has soured on market-based emissions policies. Many Democrats now favor massive spending and regulations instead.

But market-based incentives should be part of any climate legislation, for reasons of policy and politics alike. Democrats need more than their side to get a comprehensive bill. They need 10 Republican votes to reach 60 in the Senate. The only other option is using reconciliation, a parliamentary maneuver that allows budget-related bills to pass the Senate by a simple majority. But climate mandates would not qualify for reconciliation. Using reconciliation, Democrats could enact massive federal subsidies but not climate regulations. They also could impose carbon taxes, or a mix of carbon taxes and spending.

In a functional Congress, this situation would produce a deal: Mr. Romney and other GOP senators would offer a carbon tax; Democrats would insist that some of its revenue go to underserved communities and renewable energy research; the nation would get a climate plan. Mr. Romney should try. Democrats should listen. If it does not work, Democrats must find another path. One way or another, this Senate must approve a strong climate policy.

https://www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/this-congress-must-go-big-on-climate-change/2021/03/18/80dd58fc-876e-11eb-bfdf-4d36dab83a6d_story.html

Casten offers bill to slash energy industry emissions

Congressman Sean Casten’s bill is innovative but lacks comprehensive coverage of the economy. We applaud his efforts.

By Nick Sobczyk, E&E Daily, March 15, 2021

Rep. Sean Casten (D-Ill.) last week reintroduced an unorthodox carbon pricing bill that would aim to eliminate 40% of U.S. greenhouse gas emissions by 2040.

The "Tradable Performance Standards Act" would tackle the electricity sector and industrial emissions from thermal energy by effectively combining a price on carbon with a clean energy standard.

The bill would create a system of emissions allowances, declining each year, doled out to greenhouse gas emitters by EPA.

High-carbon generators would pay zero-carbon generators for allowances, pricing emissions and setting up a timeline for declines without a direct fee or a credit system for clean energy.

The idea is to use a market-based system to reduce emissions without directly raising energy prices for consumers, as with a traditional carbon tax, and without setting up a massive federal bureaucracy.

Casten said when he first introduced the legislation last year that it's the product of more than a decade of work (E&E Daily, Oct. 14, 2020).

"I want to get it out there, get it into the mix, so that when we're talking about some kind of a comprehensive energy and climate bill in the 117th Congress, we're hopefully talking about a framework like this as the way to reduce the CO2," Casten told E&E News at the time.

It's one of several carbon pricing or clean energy standard bills floating around Congress, as Democrats prepare for a push on broader climate change and infrastructure legislation in the coming months.

"Curbing climate pollution from the electric and industrial sectors is essential to tackling the climate crisis," Elizabeth Gore, senior vice president for political affairs at the Environmental Defense Fund, said in a statement.

"Rep. Casten's innovative proposal will not only cut climate pollution from these sectors, it will help spur investment in clean energy jobs and reduce harmful air pollution."

https://www.eenews.net/eedaily/2021/03/15/stories/1063727379?utm_campaign=edition&utm_medium=email&utm_source=eenews:eedaily

A simpler, more useful way to tax carbon

Though this story ran in August 2020, we believe it’s worth reading, in part because Noah Kaufman has joined the Biden administration to work on climate economics. To see the two charts mentioned in the text, go to the URL listed at the end of this story.

A new proposal for how carbon taxes can play well with other policies.

By David Roberts, Vox, August 17, 2020

For most of the 21st century, putting a price on carbon dioxide emissions (either a carbon tax or a cap-and-trade system) has been seen as the serious person’s climate-change policy, preferred by economists, claimed to have bipartisan appeal, and backed relentlessly by tribunes of Beltway conventional wisdom like the Washington Post editorial board.

In the past few years, though, carbon pricing has fallen out of favor with activists. These days, the left has aligned around standards, investments, and justice: sector-specific emissions standards, large-scale public spending on low-carbon infrastructure, and an overarching focus on the most vulnerable and hardest-hit communities.

Nonetheless, it would be wrong to say that the bulk of climate opinion has turned against carbon pricing. Relatively few people think it’s a bad or entirely useless policy. They just see it as one tool in the policy toolbox, a complement to, not a replacement for, the many other policy tools available. Climate campaigners would prefer a carbon price with more modest aspirations, designed as part of a policy portfolio.

Academia has heard this call and, lo, it hath delivered.

The latest issue of the journal Nature Climate Change contains a study that attempts to sketch out a new approach to pricing carbon, one that does not suffer from the arrogance and overreach of previous attempts. (The authors are Noah Kaufman and Peter Marsters of Columbia University’s Center on Global Energy Policy, Wojciech Krawczyk and Haewon McJeon of the University of Maryland, and Alexander R. Barron of Smith College — I’ll just call it the Kaufman paper.)

Rather than the conventional method of determining a carbon price, which involves wildly uncertain far-future climate projections from scientists and a whole range of social value judgments from economists, they advocate for a more modest approach, with prices tied to short-term goals and arrived at through democratic deliberation. It’s a refreshingly practical approach, a way to help policymakers rather than dictating to them.

Let’s look at the details. I’ll start with the big flaw of carbon pricing to date — the problem the authors are trying to solve — and then take a look at how they propose to solve it.

Cap-and-trade systems (which cap emissions and create tradable emissions credits) have largely lost their cachet. California’s system is faltering; the Northeast’s Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative is still running smoothly, but its effects are modest. Policymakers and economists have come to fear that the markets cap-and-trade creates are subject to manipulation and that they can’t ratchet toward zero emissions fast enough.

And so, what carbon-pricing action there is these days is around carbon taxes. (There are several carbon-tax proposals floating around Congress.)

Traditionally, the more enthusiastic carbon tax advocates have leaned on two flawed assumptions. The first is that there is an “optimal” price for carbon, which perfectly captures the balance between the costs of climate damages and the costs of decarbonizing. The second is that, once that price is determined, a tax on carbon is the “first best” and only necessary policy; other carbon-reduction policies will just distort the perfect market balance struck by the price.

The “optimal” carbon price is known in the biz as the “social cost of carbon” (SCC). The pretense of the social cost of carbon is that economists will add up all the projected damages of climate change to determine the all-in marginal cost of an additional ton of emissions. The tax on carbon will be set at that amount, which means we will purchase exactly as much climate mitigation as is “worth it.”

However, economists cooking up an optimal carbon price and presenting it to policymakers as a fait accompli fails to meet the public’s needs in three big ways.

First, determining climate damages is a wildly complex undertaking. It involves models built on a whole panoply of assumptions and inputs, many of which, the Kaufman paper says, are “inherently uncertain, such as the appropriate discount rates, risk aversion levels, issues around inequality, and attempts to assign monetary values to non-economic climate damages.”

Because of the complexity and uncertainties, the range of values produced by economists for the social cost range widely. “Meta-analyses find recent SCC estimates that range from under US$0 per ton of CO2 to over US$2,000 per ton,” the paper writes. Even if the outliers are excluded, estimates still range by hundreds of dollars. That doesn’t give policymakers much to go on.

Second, all of those uncertain variables — equity, the value of future generations, the value of other species — are buried in models, where they are effectively invisible to policymakers. Assigning value to these variables involves social and ethical decisions, but those decisions are being made by economists rather than through democratic deliberation. Policymakers have no real way of knowing what kinds of considerations produce what kinds of prices.

And third, the values for the social cost of carbon spit out by models have no connection to the policy goals they are meant to serve. They are not designed to achieve particular ends and their effects are uncertain, which, again, isn’t very helpful for policymakers.

The social cost produced by this contentious and values-laden process is meant to capture all the damage done by carbon emissions, meaning it is designed to be the principle, even only, carbon-reduction policy. But that assumes that unpriced carbon is the only market distortion that needs addressing, which flies in the face of real-world experience. The best economic and political theory now suggests that a portfolio approach to climate change, a broad package of policies, has the best chances of success.

But a carbon tax designed around the social costs is designed to be totalizing — it offers no guidance for how to craft a carbon price meant to complement other policies.

Kaufman and his co-authors propose an alternative design framework for a carbon tax: a near-term to net zero (NT2NZ) approach.

In a nutshell, rather than asking what the optimal carbon price is in some econo-metaphysical sense, the approach begins by asking: Given other policies in place and a reasonable set of assumptions, what price on carbon is required to drive emissions to net zero on schedule?

This approach has a number of advantages. It doesn’t require any complex calculations about the damages of climate change decades hence, so the biggest uncertainties are taken off the table and it can produce much more precise, actionable price estimates. It puts values-based decisions about social and ethical trade-offs in the hands of policymakers rather than economists. And it is reverse-engineered from specific policy goals, so it doesn’t require any guessing about its effects. In all these ways, it is much more tangibly useful to policymakers.

To see how these advantages play out, let’s look at the four steps the authors lay out for designing a near-term to net-zero carbon tax.

1) Pick a date to hit net zero

The climate situation is simple: either the world reaches net-zero carbon emissions or global temperatures keep rising forever. Every nation must reach net zero; the only choice is how fast. Different countries will move at different speeds depending on their individual circumstances, level of economic development, and risk valuations. These decisions should be made by policymakers, out in the open.

2) Craft an emissions pathway to the net-zero target

As the Kaufman paper notes, “an infinite number of pathways are conceivable between current emissions levels and a future net-zero target.” Some pathways emphasize near-term reductions. Others emphasize R&D aimed at larger reductions later. Some rely on electrification, some include biofuels, some include nuclear power, some include negative emissions. Some are “straight line” reductions, others show a peak and then a decline.

Again, decisions about the appropriate pathway should be made by policymakers, based on national circumstances and values.

3) Determine the carbon price consistent with the emissions pathway in the near term

Energy-economic models can be used to estimate a carbon price that will help meet the desired target. Unlike the models that estimate SCC, energy-economic models can integrate the effects of multiple policies, so they can show a carbon tax how to be a team player.

The models and their projections are built on assumptions about the future trajectory of energy technologies, consumer behavior, and policy. Those things are more difficult to predict the farther out in the future, so these kinds of models are generally most useful when planning for the short term, the next decade or so. Beyond that, the assumptions become educated guesses.

So Kaufman et. al recommend that the models be used to determine near-term carbon prices rather than to guess what prices might need to be in 2050. “Focusing on the near term,” they say, “means that CO2 price estimates should not be unduly influenced by assumptions about the highly uncertain long-term evolution of technologies and behavior.”

In short, they urge that plans be made based on what we can see immediately ahead of us, not hopes for technological miracles decades out.

4) Periodically repeat steps 1-3

Knowledge in the fields of climate, energy, and technology evolves rapidly; policymakers should periodically set new goals and craft new pathways based on the latest science and democratic opinion.

There are a variety of ways to do this kind of “adaptive management.” Carbon prices could be adjusted automatically based on predetermined metrics — boosted if interim emission targets are not being met, or lowered if energy prices rise too high. Or prices could be adjusted every five years through an inclusive stakeholder process.

“Pairing a long-term emissions target with a set of iterative near-term policies is not novel,” the paper says. “The United Kingdom, for example, has adopted a national target of net-zero GHG emissions by 2050 and sets five-year carbon budgets to act as stepping-stones.” This approach fits well with the Paris climate agreement, which requires countries to submit new nationally determined contributions (NDCs, or commitments to reduce greenhouse gases) every five years.

To illustrate, Kaufman et. al determine near-term to net-zero carbon prices for the US that would yield straight-line emission reductions to a series of net-zero targets.

The chart below tells the tale. On the left, you can see the emission pathways to net-zero in 2040, 2050, and 2060 respectively. On the right, you can see the carbon prices necessary to reach those targets: $32, $52, and $93 per metric ton in 2025, with prices almost double that in 2030.

The black bar lines on the right-hand chart represent the range of carbon tax proposals currently before Congress, revealing that the near-term to net-zero prices are roughly within the range of what lawmakers are discussing.

As the colored bars on the right show, each estimate is actually a fairly wide range. That has to do with the sensitivity of models to a variety of assumptions, from the cost of various energy sources to the rate of innovation to the success of complementary policies. If any of those variables unfold differently than Kaufman et al. have projected, then the carbon price estimates would change accordingly.

The chart below shows how much changes in these variables affect the final price estimates. As you can see, a great deal depends on the price of oil and the success of other policies, both of which are extremely difficult to predict.

Setting near-term to net-zero carbon prices is not easy. It still requires tons of judgment calls about future developments. But at least this approach puts those judgment calls on the table where policymakers can see them.

The near-term to net-zero model has a great deal to recommend it over the conventional social cost of carbon method. It is a more modest approach to carbon pricing, more iterative, cooperative, transparent, and democratic. It is much more concretely helpful to policymakers than the endless cosmic quest to determine a precise social cost.

In a sense, however, its strengths are also its vulnerabilities. All those value-laden decisions previously made by economists in spreadsheets would be open to public dispute and manipulation. Every time policymakers revisited the tax, it would be a chance for vested interests to make mischief and complicate it with exemptions and conditions.

Basically, the near-term to net-zero approach exposes carbon pricing directly to democracy. Whether you think that’s a good idea or not depends on your assessment of the health of the world’s big democracies. There is certainly a school of thought that says complex decisions like this should be made by experts — something like California’s model, where the state legislature sets broad targets and direction and the Air Resources Board carries them out.

But if the world is truly to reach net zero, all the world’s polities will eventually have to buy into the effort. It can’t be done successfully if driven purely from the top down. When polities and policymakers are ready, they will find a carbon price a helpful tool, and the modest approach is a helpful way of crafting one.

https://www.vox.com/energy-and-environment/2020/8/17/21370732/carbon-tax-simple-useful-nt2nz

Senators float a price on methane to curb U.S. oil, gas emissions

By Valerie Volcovici, Reuters, March 9, 2021

WASHINGTON - Three Democratic U.S. senators on Tuesday floated a bill that would take a new approach to curbing emissions from methane from oil and gas production - putting a price on it.

Senators Sheldon Whitehouse, Cory Booker and Brian Schatz introduced the Methane Emissions Reduction Act, which directs the Department of Treasury to assess a fee on the potent greenhouse gas beginning in 2023 - a move they say could end those emissions, help achieve climate change targets and improve air quality in communities near oil and gas facilities.

The bill also calls on Treasury to work with the Environmental Protection Agency and the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration to develop a program to monitor and measure methane emissions from each major oil producing basin.

“This bill will hold oil and gas companies financially responsible for their methane pollution and make methane emissions from fossil fuel production cost prohibitive, steps that will go a long way in the fight against climate change and to protect air quality in local communities,” Booker said.

National Climate Adviser Gina McCarthy said the Biden administration is working to propose new regulations here to curb methane emissions on federal and private land by September, replacing and strengthening regulations that the Trump administration had revoked.

Special Climate Envoy John Kerry has said the U.S. will work to align methane regulation with other countries here, such as Canada.

The fee the bill envisions would be assessed on a basin-by-basin basis and cover all companies that produce, gather, process, or transmit oil or natural gas, the senators said, and would be based on a formula factoring in the company’s gas production and methane rate.

Companies that already voluntarily reduce methane will be able to opt out of the fee by demonstrating their emissions intensity is below the average of the operating basin.

Funds raised from the fee go into the National Coastal Resilience Fund, a program administered by the National Fish and Wildlife Foundation and NOAA to prepare communities for climate change.

https://www.reuters.com/article/us-usa-climate-methane-idUSKBN2B12O4?utm_source=newsletter&utm_medium=email&utm_campaign=newsletter_axiosgenerate&stream=top